This website uses cookies to ensure you get the best experience on our website. Learn more

#10849 - Theories Of The Corporation - Business Associations 1

Notice: PDF Preview
The following is a more accessible plain text extract of the PDF sample above, taken from our Business Associations 1 Notes. Due to the challenges of extracting text from PDFs, it will have odd formatting.
See Original

[2.200] Positions and practices – The CB writers postulate that if managers are free from shareholder controls, how are corporate goals defined?

  • Empirically, do managers substitute other priorities – of personal interests, the corporate organization or of society? And

  • Normatively, what goals ought corporate managers adopt in their discharge of corporate social responsibility – just strict profit maximization, social amelioration or something in between?

  • Doctrinally, What interests does the law enjoy directors to serve and what limits are set on ‘corporate altruism’

  • Directors have the ultimate discretion about how to achieve goals of profit maximization and shareholder wealth but they are not free to act for a fundamentally different purpose

    • However, as a social and economic institution they must comply with the law and adhere to ethical considerations and public welfare claims within limits of responsible conduct

  • Two competing claims, that of Berle (that company’s act solely for their shareholders) and Dodd (expounding a managerialist ethic of a corporation affected not only by laws but by the attitude of the public and business opinion as to their social obligations)

    • On the second view the corporate personality is a ‘professional’ even though its stockholders are not – and hence it can employ its funds in a manner appropriate to a person practicing a profession and imbued with a sense of social responsibility without being guilty of breach of trust

    • Eventually Berle was to agree with Dodd and claim that a corporate conscience had evolved in the US [p 70.9] – these statements stand completely contrary to economist Milton Friedman’s statement that “the social responsibility of business is to increase its profit”

  • This model of ‘business statesmanship’ has been variously adopted around the world

    • A centrel tenet is that management owes duties beyond the corporations legal constitutes to the ‘four parties to industry’ – labour, capital, management and the community (and perhaps government, suppliers and consumers)

    • The management function is to allocate corporate resources between competing interest groups to achieve both corporate and public goals

    • The Confederation of British Industry proposed adoption of similar guidelines of companies to recognize the obligations arising from relationships with all such groups to strike a balance between their interests and that of the company proprietors

    • In Australia these principles of Corporate Social Responsibility are expressed in the ASX Corporate Governance Principles and Recommendations including

      • Principle 3 “Companies should promote ethical and responsible decision-making” – such decisions should not only comply with legal obligations but reasonable expectations of stakeholders (shareholders, employees, customers, suppliers etc.)

      • Recommendation 7.1 – listed companies should “establish polices for the oversight and management of material business risks and disclose a summary of those polices” – such risks include “operational, environmental, sustainability...etc.

        • These are not mandatory but listing rules require that companies disclose in annual reports the extent to which they have followed the ASX principles during the reporting period and giving reasons for not doing so (ASXLR 4.10.3)

What corporate social responsibility might mean (if it were to really matter)

  • There are no settled definitions to CSR – different variants would have different implications – e.g. those permitting directors to have regard to non-shareholders interests and those imposing a duty to do so

  • Redmond says the real question is whether directors should have a license or a duty to sacrifice shareholder interests for the common good/third parties

    • This generally depends on perceptions as to the efficiency and equity of markets for satisfying social goals

    • It also evokes distinctions between private and public character of corporations

  • [2.206] Shareholder Primacy - This conception is based on the idea that the overriding objective of all companies is “the preservation and the greatest practical enhancement over time of their shareholders’ investment” (Hampel Committee UK, 1998)

    • It is based on the assumption that the duty of management is to maximize the wealth of their principal – shareholders – and corporate law works to promote this end

    • Such a claim is usually based on the fact that:

      • Shareholders are the ultimate risk bearers (ranking after debtors in claims)

      • Their entitlement to surplus income during the firm’s life

      • Their monopoly of voting rights and of the right to sell control of the company through disposal of assets, and monopoly rights to bring suit for wrongs suffered by the company which it hasn’t sought to vindicate

    • These justifications are disputed on a number of grounds including:

      • That it will allow the externalization of costs of operations *(e.g. environmental costs) NOTE FOOTNOTE 174

        • O: This is a failure of allocating property rights, not the corporate form

        • The incentive to dos o will arise since if companies voluntarily assume social costs it might effectively externalise, it risks its long term survival against competitors

  • [2.207] Pluralist/multifiduciary models – this model creates a multifiduciary duty requiring directors and managers to run the company in the interest of all those with a stake in its success – balancing the claims of competing stakeholders (employees, the community etc.), each of which are recognized as valuable in their own right

    • These models are often based on a theory of the corporation as a ‘community’ that responds to the harm to which other stakeholders are exposed by a management focus on solely shareholder interests

      • Such a theory was popularized in the takeover boom of the 1980s to which communitarians responded by saying that the post-acquisition gains for shareholders was achieved through wealth transfers from non-shareholders (lenders assuming additional debt, employees who made years of human capital investments etc.) [adopted in many US states – see p73.5]

    • The case for the idea that directors can sacrifice shareholder interests from the ‘complexity of social and economic organisation and from assumptions as to regulatory overload upon the modern state’

      • That is all the forms of market failure are impossible for the state to respond to in a timely fashion; thus management should have a duty/license to allocate resources to achieving such social benefits at the expense of shareholder welfare

    • But there are problems:

      • Articulating corporate standards – the primacy model is clearly defined and enforceable – outside of this it is hard to construct a new attractive/logical framework

      • The legitimacy of management powers – why are corporate managers better attuned to making these decisions than other individuals and the responsible/representative government

  • [2.208] Corporate social responsibility and directors duties – such questions as to these were highlighted by the corporate restructuve of James Hardie and the inadequate resourcing of asbestos subsidiaries severed from the group to pay compensation

    • Hardie lawyers advised the BOD that their duties as directors precluded them from making voluntary payments to those suffering asbestos-related illnesses of their subsidiaries unless it was for the benefit of shareholders. Two inquires were prompted:

      • The Parliamentary Joint Committee on Corporate and Financial Services – which opposed amending directors’ duties to expressly allow regard to non-stakeholders; they thought AU corporate law already allows this. They expressed support for the idea of ‘sustainability reporting’ (but not that it be mandatory)

      • The Corporations and Markets Advisory Committee – considered the current formulation of director’s duties was flexible enough for directors to take non-shareholder interests into account. They should be able to do so in their self-interest but not obliged to. They thought that allowing directors to address social/environmental issues would introduce difficulties to their role/accountability to shareholders

        • They also expressed the idea that if any problems as to social/environmental impacts could not be resolved by the market, specific legislation should be enacted

    • Cf the UK where an ‘inclusive’ approach to directors duties was adopted – rejecting the ‘plural approach’ they adopted what they called “enlightened shareholder value” which addressed the problem of indeterminate DM criteria by privileging shareholder interest over that of other stakeholders (but these interests are to be considered insofar as they promote shareholder interests)

      • The so-called ‘enlightenment’ was that stakeholders had to be scanned for impacts in order to extract maximum shareholder advantage

      • Rather than negatives to stakeholders being weighed directly against shareholder benefit (pluralist) it is part of the calculus of considering shareholder advantage

  • [2.209] Redmond mentions that the questions posed above inherently depend on the conception of a publicly held corporation. WT Allen identifies two distinct conceptions which are “each conditioned on a different idea of what it means to be a human being in society”

    • The classical liberal paradigm – the social world is populated by rational individuals pursuing their own vision of the good life. Legal institutions are to keep the peace,...

Unlock the full document,
purchase it now!
Business Associations 1
Target a first in law with Oxbridge